Source of Book: Borrowed from the library
I didn’t really intend to read another food related book so soon after The American Way of Eating, but my wife already had this checked out, and liked it. I figured I might as well read it while we still had it.
Tyler
Cowen is a professor of economics at George Mason University, writes
for a number of publications, professional and general, and has two
blogs: one about economics, and one about food.
Cowen’s
concept in this book is a little unclear. The subtitle is “New Rules
for Everyday Foodies,” but the book doesn’t really contain rules as much
as his concepts of what makes good food and how to find it, combined
with some of his ideas on the economics of food. This does not mean that
the book is mediocre, exactly. On the contrary, it is interesting,
informative, accurate for the most part, and is improved by its lack of a
solid “point.” One of my complaints about many modern non-fiction books
is the need that the publishers feel to make the book have a moral, or a
solution to the problems presented, or some singular focus. Often, the
best thing a book can do is present a compelling story or issue, give
some information regarding the problem that is probably not familiar to
the reader, and let the reader draw a conclusion.
In
a book like this, where the aim of the reader is to discover something
about food and economics, the last thing needed is a list of hard and
fast “rules” that probably will not work for the reader in every
situation. Instead, this book is full of stories and thoughts on how the
writer found good food around the world, which makes for an interesting
read by itself, and gave me some ideas for future travel.
I
will confess that I am a foodie. I have cooked ever since I was around
seven or eight, and still needed a chair to see the top of the stove. By
ten or so, I was cooking an occasional meal with just a little
supervision, and started cooking for my family a few times a month in my
teens. I informed my wife when we were contemplating marriage that we
would have to share the kitchen, and that I expected to cook regularly.
As it turns out, we are both happy with an even split of the cooking -
and we certainly eat well as a result. Cooking and eating are both
important to my life, and I find that food draws people together.
The
combination of my love for food and my inherent cheapness - I *cough*
mean frugality - I have generally aimed to find food with value when I
eat out. There is the occasional splurge, but I try to find
out-of-the-way places with interesting and unusual food.
The
author of this book has largely the same idea, and has made it his aim
in this book to show how to find inexpensive but highly delicious food.
The basic rule that he sets out is this:
Food
is a product of economic supply and demand, so try to figure out where
the supplies are fresh, the suppliers are creative, and the demanders
are informed.
The
rest of his suggestions follow from this idea. If there is only one
Chinese restaurant in town, and few Chinese patrons, the food is likely
terrible, for example. This one is certainly true. Conversely, good
seafood is typically found next to the ocean, where there is plenty of
competition, and more locals than tourists.
Some
of his specific suggestions were spot on. I live near enough to the Los
Angeles area (where I grew up) to be able to eat in the “Thai Town”
section of east Hollywood. The author recommends this area, and he is
certainly right. I have never had Thai food that good anywhere - except
the times I have had home made food from friends.
Also
following from the basic rule is that social status in a restaurant
brings a price, both monetary and culinary. Once a restaurant has a
reputation of a place to meet others and hob-nob, it has less incentive
to keep the food good. The patrons have a different goal than good,
inexpensive food.
Along
with this argument is the idea of “price subsidies.” In the “old days,”
airline fares were fixed by law, so competition was on service only.
Thus, the high fixed ticket prices subsidized the cost of good food.
Likewise, Starbucks (and similar businesses) can be a good source of
high-quality coffee, subsidized by the more expensive sugary drinks.
In
addition to the sections of the book devoted to the tips for the
pursuit of good food, there are also interesting sections on other areas
in which economics and gastronomy intersect.
Cowen
seeks to disprove the three great myths of food snobbery. First, that
the best food is also the most expensive. This is related to the idea
that only “slow food” is best. Second, that large agribusiness is
irredeemably bad. Third, that consumers not a trusted source of
innovation, but must be controlled and nudged by various “experts,”
particularly those in political office. This review doesn’t have the
space for Cowen’s arguments, but they are worth a read.
Some
of these arguments, naturally, get a little political. Depending on
one’s views, his ideas will be more or less persuasive. In any event,
they are thought provoking, and are based in economic theory, so they
are not particularly partisan arguments.
Two
examples are particularly interesting to me. First is his argument in
favor of genetically modified foods. Again, I do not have time to
reiterate his arguments, but I found them to be a breath of fresh air
after all of the overheated rhetoric and scare tactics. A quick example
here is interesting. Most of the hype is about Mosanto’s products that
are resistant to the use of herbicides, allowing them to be sprayed
wholesale without being killed. This would, presumably, result in more
herbicide in the plant itself. Of course, such products could not be
labeled as organic anyway, so they would be easy to avoid for that
reason. The author’s point, however, is that the more common reason to
modify a crop is so that it needs less
herbicide or pesticide use. This would be of particular benefit to poor
nations unable to afford the extensive infrastructure necessary to
support widespread spraying. Again, one may or may not agree with his
position, but he does lay out the economics of the issue in a
non-alarmist manner.
The
second example involves the use of carbon taxes - a big issue right now
of course - to make it easier to estimate the environmental impact of
food choices. Personally, I am unconvinced that carbon usage is a big
evil to be eliminated, but I do appreciate his point that this is the
best economic way to reduce carbon emissions. Essentially, right now, it
is pretty much impossible to determine what the energy cost of any
given food or packaging is. One can see the total
cost to the supplier, but not what lies behind it. Indeed, with the
extended food supply chains we have, no one person has all the
information at hand. By taxing energy (or carbon emissions) one adds to
the cost of that element of the total cost, making it matter to the
consumer more than it does now. (This is based on the well proven idea
that there are two costs to everything: the direct cost, which is clear
from the price; and the indirect costs, like pollution, which are not
borne by the consumer, but by society at large. By charging for the
indirect costs through either taxes or regulation, the consumer is made
to pay an amount closer to the sum of both costs.) Again, it depends on
whether you agree with the basic premise.
I
want to make a gratuitous mention of the source of the Mexican cheese
industry, which is used as an example of which food is better eaten in
Mexico than in El Paso. It was a group of Mennonite immigrants that got
the whole thing started. Since I have Mennonite ancestry on both sides
of my family, I found this interesting.
As
a final point, I want to mention the author’s theory as to the reasons
that so much of American food is lousy, and how it got that way. The
author thinks that the confluence of four factors changed American food
in the 1940s and thereafter.
First
was Prohibition. I have written elsewhere that I believe the two
greatest scourges of the American nation were slavery and Prohibition. I
believe that they were, together, the source of much of our current
obesity epidemic. This book gives me even more reasons to reinforce my
opinion. In essence, the author argues that most of the truly good
restaurants in the larger cities were dependent on wine and beer sales
for their profit margin. (This holds true today as well.) Also, much
fine cuisine just goes better with alcohol. Prohibition drove the good
establishments out of business, and those that defied the law had to
focus on provision of booze and hiding from the law, rather good food.
The
second factor was the industrialization caused by World War Two. The
United States is pretty good at creating industrial processes, and the
war cause a need to develop such for food preservation.
The
third factor was the early Twentieth Century crackdown on immigration.
Total numbers of immigrants fell dramatically with the new quotas, and
therefore, our biggest source of food innovation dried up. The
exception, of course, was immigrants from Mexico and further south,
which have always crossed, legally or illegally, in great numbers. This
explains why decent Mexican influenced food is available throughout the
Southwest, but good food from most other places is only now making a
comeback.
The
final factor is our tendency to cater to our children’s preferences for
bad food. I am happy to say that there are at least a few of us who
expect our kids to eat what we eat. However, the damage was done, and
there is no end of chicken strips and mac ‘n’ cheese wherever one goes
in this nation.
I think in light of the thoroughly ghastly food that took hold in the 1950s, the author has a point here.
Summary:
an interesting, thoughtful read, with enough food ideas to cause
drooling, and enough economics to inspire a evaluation of one’s
perspective.
Ooo. Another one to mark down to read. (I did purchase that one on fonts for a Christmas surprise. It's hidden away.)
ReplyDeleteTHIS title sounds like it's up my alley!